CHAP. V. of Advanced International Relations

CHAP V. CHANGING BALANCE OF THE GLOBAL ECONOMY

V.0 Introduction

Profound changes have been taking place in the global economy over the past two decades.

First, trade and financial linkages between developed countries, the North, and developing countries, the South, have become much stronger. Second, a number of developing countries have differentiated themselves from the others in the South by growing at an extraordinary pace while rapidly integrating them-selves into the global economy. Moreover, some of these developing economies have become increasingly important players in the global economy as they have begun to account for a substantial share of the world output.

Understanding the implications of these changes is important for the design of macroeconomic policies and theoretical models. Deeper trade and financial integration between the North and South can generate faster cross-border transmission of macroeconomic fluctuations, and therefore, can have implications for international coordination of economic policies. In regards to the theory, a better understanding of international economic linkages could be helpful in the design of dynamic models that can replicate the changing nature of linkages between the North and South.

As we review in Section II, there has been a growing empirical research program analysing the linkages between the developed economies of the North and the developing countries of the South. Our study contributes to this research program along several dimensions. First, to have a better understanding of the changing nature of linkages between these two groups, we examine sectoral interactions in addition to the conventional macroeconomic channels of interdependence.

The earlier literature on the North-South linkages has mostly focused on the channels of transmission considering fluctuations in the standard macroeconomic aggregates, such as output, consumption, and investment. The sectorial analysis allows us to study the implications of dramatic shifts across industry, service, and agriculture sectors that have taken place over the past two decades.

Second, we employ a comprehensive dataset of 106 countries covering the 1960–2005 periods. Considering the changes that have taken place over this period, we analyse the North- South linkages in three distinct sub-periods. The first period of 1960–72 corresponds to the Bretton Woods fixed exchange rate regime. The second period of 1973–85 is associated with a number of common shocks, including sharp fluctuations in the price of oil in the 1970s and contractionary (and highly synchronous) monetary policies in major industrial economies in the early 1980s. Finally, the third period, 1986–2005, represents the globalization era where there has been a substantial increase in the volume of trade and financial flows.

By opening their trade and capital accounts during the globalization period, a number of emerging market economies have differentiated themselves from other developing countries in the South.3 this observation is directly related to our third contribution, as discussed below.

In Section III, we examine how the size distribution of these groups and the dynamics of sectoral output, trade and financial linkages have evolved over time. Our results suggest that the Emerging South economies have increasingly become major players in the global economy because of their rapid economic growth fuelled by the dramatic changes in their sectoral structure and international trade and financial linkages. As a result of these changes, the nature of interactions between the Emerging South and North has evolved from one of dependence to multifaceted interdependence.

We turn our attention to the dynamics of growth linkages across these groups in Section IV.
The results indicate that there has been a noticeable pattern of convergence within each group of the North and Emerging South countries during the globalization period. In particular, growth fluctuations in aggregate output and production of industry and service sectors across the North countries have become more correlated. Similarly, the growth rates of output and industrial production of the Emerging South economies have become more strongly associated with those of their Emerging Southern trading partners.

Surprisingly, cross-group correlations of growth fluctuations suggest that the Emerging South economic activity has appeared to diverge (or decouple) from that of the North in the globalization period. While these are useful stylized facts about the transmission of fluctuations across these three groups, understanding the changing nature of growth spillovers requires a formal framework controlling numerous other factors. We tackle these issues in Section V.

In particular, Section V analyses the evolving nature of growth spillovers across these three groups using a panel regression model that allows us to control for other growth determinants as well as common shocks. Our results suggest that the North economies have continued to play a dominant role in explaining the growth dynamics in the rest of the world during the globalization period. However, consistent with the stylized facts about the transmission of growth fluctuations documented above, the impact of the North on the growth dynamics of the Emerging South has declined in the globalization period relative to the earlier periods.

V.I The North-South Linkeges
There have been three streams of empirical research studying the implications of increasing trade and financial flows for the nature of cyclical and growth linkages between the developing countries of the North and the developing economies of the South. The first stream has merely focused on the changes in the time-series patterns of the interdependency across the North and South.

The second stream of the literature has attempted to measure the magnitude of spillovers between the North and South. The third one has analysed the determinants of the business cycle co-movement among countries and groups.

V.I.1 Characterizing the North-South Economic Linkages OverTime
Kose, Otrok, and Prasad (2007) examine the sources of macroeconomic fluctuations in the developed economies of the North and the developing countries of the South using dynamic factor models and the series of output, consumption, and investment for the 1960–2005 period.4 They explicitly separate the group of emerging markets from other developing economies in the South.

They find that while the global factor accounts for a smaller share of business cycle variation in the globalization period, the factors capturing the common fluctuations in each group have become more important in the groups of developed and emerging market countries over time. In other words, intra-group business cycles have become more potent over time in these groups of countries.

Hoffmaister, Pradhan, and Samiei (1998) analyze the long-run growth linkages between the
North and South using annual data for the 1967–1993 periods by constructing group specific output aggregates. They show that despite the long term co-integrating relationship between the growth dynamics of the two groups, the influence of the North countries on the output growth of the South countries has declined over time. They also document a potential structural break in the North-South relationship around the late 1980s. In addition, they report that the South, especially Asia, has become more resilient to cyclical movements in the North possibly because of structural changes that have taken place among the emerging Asian economies over the last decades.

There are three papers focusing on the degree of business cycle co-movement across developed and developing countries using sectoral data. Kouparitsas (2001) documents various stylized facts about the linkages between cyclical growth fluctuations of the Northern and Southern sectoral activity for the 1970–1995 period using annual growth rates. 

Loayza, Lopez, and Ubide (2001) analyze the common economic patterns across countries in Latin America, East Asia, and Europe for the period of 1970–1994 by means of an error components model. Their model decomposes annual real value added growth of GDP, industry, services and agriculture in each country into international, sectoral, and country specific effects. They find that growth fluctuations in the European and East Asian countries exhibit a significantly high degree of co-movement.

V.I.2 Quantifying the Extent of Linkages between the North and South
Some recent papers examine the role of trade partners’ economic performance in driving the dynamics of growth. For example, Arora and Vamvakidis (2004) study the role of trade partners in driving the medium term economic growth using a fixed effects panel regression model for 101 countries for the period of 1960–1999. They find that the industrial countries of the North benefit from trading with the rapidly growing developing countries in the South while developing countries benefit from trading with the relatively high-income industrial economies in the North. Their results indicate that a one percentage point increase in the average growth of a country’s trading partners increases domestic growth 0.8 percentage points over a 5-year period even after controlling for the global and group-wide trends.6

In a companion paper, Arora and Vamvakidis (2006) estimate the impact of the U.S. economy on the growth performance of a large sample of industrial and developing countries using a fixed-effects panel regression model for the period of 1980–98. Their results suggest that a one percentage point increase in the U.S. growth is associated with an average of one percentage point increase in the growth in other countries even when the non- U.S. world growth or growth in Japan and Europe is included in the regression.

Helbling and others (2007) examine the implications of a possible economic slowdown in the U.S. economy for other countries using a variety of empirical methods. They find that while the potential size of spillovers from the United States to other countries has increased with greater trade and financial integration, the importance of these links should not be overestimated. Spillovers are most important for countries with close trade and financial ties with the United States, particularly Latin America and some industrial countries, and they tend to be larger during recessions, when import growth turns sharply negative, than during mid-cycle slowdowns.

V.I.3 Determining the Underlying Forces of Business Cycle Co-movement
There is a complementary strand of literature examining the importance of various channels underlying the co-movement of business cycles. For example, Frankel and Rose (1998),
Kose and Yi (2006) and Baxter and Kouparitsas (2005) find that trade integration plays an important role in driving business cycle co-movement. Imbs (2004 and 2006) emphasizes the importance of sectoral similarity in addition to trade flows.

Darvas, Rose, and Szapáry (2005) and Clark and van Wincoop (2001) provide some support for the role of policy coordination in explaining business cycle co-movement. In a recent paper, Akin (2006) provides a detailed analysis of a number of channels in driving business cycle co-movement. Using the data of a large group of industrialized and developing economies, she shows that trade linkages, especially in the form of intra-industry trade, are the main determinants of cyclical co-movement.

In addition, there are numerous studies analyzing the dynamics of business cycle co-movement in certain regions. Rana (2006 and 2007) argues that increased intra-industry trade flows and financial integration along with monetary policy coordination in East Asia have resulted in stronger cross-correlations of business cycles for some countries in the region.

Shin and Wang (2004) also find that the relationship between trade and business cycle co-movement in Asia is mainly driven by the extent of intra-industry trade flows. Kumakura (2006) emphasizes the importance of electronics industry in driving cross-country business cycle correlations in Asia.

V.II Evolution of International Economic Linkages
This section starts with a detailed analysis of the size distribution of countries in the three groups and their growth dynamics. Next, it examines how international trade and financial linkages have evolved over time. It then provides a brief discussion of the implications of these changes for the traditional models of North-South growth linkages.

V.II.1 Changes in the Size of Distribution of Countries
The world economy has witnessed a dramatic shift in the size distribution of countries in the globalization period. To analyze these changes, we first divide the world (106 countries) into three groups of countries. The North is composed of 23 “core” OECD countries, the Emerging South includes 23 emerging markets, and the Developing South contains 60 developing countries. The group of Emerging South countries constitutes relatively more mature emerging markets in the sense that they attract the lion’s share of international financial flows to developing countries.

Available statistics indicate that during the period of 1960–85, the North economies on average constituted more than 70 percent of the world GDP (in PPP terms) while the share of the Emerging South was roughly 25 percent. During the globalization period, the share of the Emerging South has increased to 34 percent while the Northern share has decreased to 62 percent. The share of the Developing South has registered a slight decline over time. These changes have mainly been the result of vibrant growth in the Emerging South in recent decades.

Also, the average growth in this group of countries has been more than two times faster than that in the North during the globalization period. The increase in the share of the Emerging South in the world GDP has been primarily driven by China and India. For example, China’s share of world GDP has increased dramatically from 3.17 percent during the Bretton Woods period to 9.79 percent in the globalization period. Similarly, the share of India has risen from 4.36 percent to 5.61 percent over these periods.

V.II.2 Changes in the Dynamics of Trade and Sectoral Output

V.II.2.1 Trade Openness
There have been significant changes in the volume and nature of trade flows during the globalization period. These changes have been fueled by the liberalization of trade policies around the world and rapid declines in the costs of transportation and communication.
In fact, the fraction of countries with a fully liberalized trade regime has precipitously increased in the globalization period. The measure of trade openness for the world has been relatively stable until 1985, but then has gained momentum during the globalization period.

In particular, the ratio for the Emerging South has risen from 28 percent to 78 percent over this period. Similarly, for the North, the openness measure has increased from 26 percent to 46 percent during the globalization period. In contrast, the openness ratio for the Developing South has been rather stable over time. Relatively high level of trade openness of this group is the result of its heavy dependence on the exports of primary commodities and fuels.

V.II.2.2 Sectoral Changes
One particular reason for the dramatic increase in the degree of openness of the Emerging South is that many economies in this group have pursued aggressive industrialization policies based on export driven growth strategies over the last two decades (see Weiss, 2005). In the 1960–1972 period, the average growth of exports of this group was lower than that of the North, but during the globalization period, it has been more than two times higher.

These developments have been accompanied by a substantial reallocation of resources from agriculture to industry and services.
Research finds reveals that the North has been rapidly increasing the relative share of services sector while the Emerging South has been allocating more resources towards industry and services. These two sectors have been the driving forces of the growth in the Emerging South. The Developing South, on the other hand, has continued to retain a relatively large agricultural sector during the globalization period.

V.II.2.3 Nature of Trade
There has also been a concurrent shift in the comparative advantage of the Emerging South from primary commodities to a diversified range of manufacturing products. The IMF working paper of 2007, documents that during the Bretton Woods period, the groups of the Emerging South and Developing South have been similar in terms of the composition of their exports and imports.

In particular, both groups have mainly been the exporters of primary commodities with the export share of 60 percent for the Emerging South and 81 percent for the Developing South while the manufacturing products have constituted the bulk of their imports. However, in the Emerging South, the share of commodities has declined to 17 percent while the share of manufacturing exports has rapidly increased to 74 percent of the total exports during the globalization period.

The share of manufacturing imports has expanded simultaneously with the growth of the manufacturing exports in the Emerging South. One of the underlying factors behind this trend has been the rising intra-industry trade between the North and Emerging South groups during the globalization period. 12 The intra-industry trade intensity with the G-7 countries has been higher for the Emerging Asia in comparison to other Emerging South countries.

The surge in intra-industry trade linkages between the North and Emerging South has been partly driven by the relocation of some Northern industrial facilities to the Emerging South. Increased intra-industry trade with the North has also led to a significant change in the direction of trade flows around the world. As shown in Figure 3, the North has remained to be the dominant destination of global trade flows during the 1960–2005 periods. The share of total world trade directed towards the Emerging South has significantly increased from 14 percent in 1985 to 25 percent in 2005. In testimony to the overall trade integration, the Emerging South has also become an important market for the North by increasing its share from 13 percent of the total Northern trade in 1985 to 21 percent in 2005.

V.II.2.4 South-South Trade Linkages
The intensity of intra- and cross-group trade linkages has increased in the South. For example, the share of intra-group trade in the total trade of the Emerging
South trade has increased by fourfold from 9 percent in 1960 to 36 percent in 2005. During this period, the share of the Emerging Southern trade with the North has declined from 83 percent to 50 percent. Similarly, in the total trade of Developing South, the share of trade with the Emerging South has jumped from 6 percent in 1960 to 25 percent in 2005. China has been an engine of the growth of intraregional trade in Asia.

For example, China related intraregional trade flows grew by 12 times trade accounting for roughly 60 percent of intraregional trade within emerging Asia over the period 1990-2006 (see Hori, 2007).
A significant fraction of intra-group trade flows in the Emerging South has been driven by intra-industry trade. Table 5 shows that intra-industry trade intensity of the Asian countries with the Emerging Asia has increased over time and it has in some cases exceeded the levels of Asian intra-industry trade with the G-7 in the 1990s. For example, within emerging Asia, China has been a major player in the growth of intra-industry trade as the index of intra industry trade intensity between China and emerging Asia has increased from 0.06 to 0.32.
V.II.3 Changes in Financial Linkages

V.II.3.1 Financial Openness
The growth of international financial flows has overshadowed that of trade flows in the globalization period. This unprecedented change has been mainly associated with the rapid liberalization of capital account regimes since 1986. Figure 1 shows that the fraction of countries with liberalized financial systems has sharply increased in the globalization period.

In addition, several “pull” and “push” factors have changed the composition of financial linkages between the North and South during the globalization period. As a consequence, the composition of capital flows, in particular to the Emerging South, has rapidly changed, and portfolio-equity and foreign direct investment inflows have become more prominent.

IMF displays the absolute level of integration of different country groups into global financial markets, calculated as the sum of gross international financial assets and liabilities.
While the level of integration is clearly highest for the North economies, the Emerging South countries have accounted for the bulk of the integration experienced by the South. The gross stocks of assets and liabilities of the Emerging South has risen by more than fivefold and has been on average an order of magnitude larger than that of the Developing South during the globalization period.

As far as the evolution of the composition of total foreign assets and liabilities for different groups of countries is concerned, among the North economies, the biggest increase has been in the share of portfolio equity during the globalization period. The share of debt in gross stocks of foreign assets and liabilities of the Emerging South has declined from 80 percent to 50 percent during the same period while the share of FDI and portfolio equity has risen from a total of 13 percent to 40 percent. The share of portfolio equity has been rather small in the total stocks of the Developing South. Accumulation of official international reserves has recently accounted for a significant portion of the increase in gross foreign assets of the Emerging and Developing South economies (see Kose and others, 2006).

V.II.3.2 South-South Financial Linkages
Finally, there are also signs of increasing financial linkages between the Emerging South and Developing South groups commensurate with the rising importance of Emerging South in the global economy. For example, intra-South FDI flows increased by threefold over the period 1995–2003 (see World Bank, 2006; and Aykut and Goldstein, 2007).

The share of flows from the Emerging South rose from 16 percent in 1995 to 36 percent in 2003 in the total FDI flows of the Developing South. These flows have mainly concentrated in the services and extractive industries backed by various government incentives for the Emerging Southern multinationals. The Emerging South banks have also started penetrating into the markets of the Developing South countries.

V.II.3.3 South-south and Triangular Linkages
In a broad sense, triangular co-operation may be understood as a type of development co-operation involving three partners. We focus on partnerships between DAC Donors and Providers of South-South Co-operation to implement development co-operation programmes/projects in Beneficiary Countries. Triangular Cooperation and Aid Effectiveness

V.II.3.4 Characterize the North-South Linkages “Theory and Evidence”
The dynamics of linkages between the North and South have been traditionally described as a form of “unidirectional dependence” with cyclical fluctuations and growth in the South being determined primarily by the developments in the North.

According to the standard North-South model (see Findlay, 1980), the North wields greater economic influence on the South because of the Southern structural dependence on the Northern capital goods, finance, technology, and export markets. The asymmetric interaction between the two groups stems from the fact that the South is composed of poor developing countries specialized in the production and export of a narrow range of primary commodities while the North is composed of rich industrialized economies specialized in the production and export of manufacturing goods. In this traditional framework, the growth in the South is driven by the Northern demand for the Southern exports which are used as inputs in the Northern manufacturing sector. The growth spillovers across these groups are transmitted primarily through terms of trade fluctuations.

The rapid diversification of the export base and industrial structure of the Emerging South towards the manufacturing activity has wide-ranging implications. For example, it indicates that the pattern of international division of labor described by the traditional framework has been changing. In particular, the Emerging South trade with the North has evolved from trade of raw materials to intra-industry trade where imported manufacturing goods from the
Emerging South economies are used as intermediate products in the North. As a consequence of this, economic spillovers between the North and Emerging South have become more interdependent. Moreover, there has been a concurrent increase in trade flows among the Emerging South countries leading to stronger intra-group spillovers.

The changes in the volume and composition of financial flows have also affected the nature of financial interactions between the North and Emerging South groups. The South experience with financial flows from the North in the traditional framework was characterized by the dominance of debt flows and official lending and the sensitivity of these flows to interest rates in the North economies before the globalization period With the rapid growth of portfolio-equity flows, fluctuations in financial markets in the North and Emerging South have become more interlinked as financial flows have become sensitive not just to the risk and return conditions of the recipient economies but also to macroeconomic conditions in the North.

In addition, cross-country international equity holdings have made asset prices in the Emerging South more responsive to financial conditions not only in the North but also in other Emerging South economies, as evidenced by the contagious nature of the 1997–98
Asian crisis.

In conclusion, the changes that have taken place in the globalization period imply that the venues of interaction between the North and Emerging South have become diversified and the relationship between these two groups has become more symmetric and interdependent in comparison to that between the North and Developing South groups. We now turn our focus to the implications of these changes for the growth linkages across these three groups of countries.

V.II.3.4 The Changing Global Economic Landscape
Driven by technological changes that have reduced the costs of communication and transportation, a dramatic increase in the world supply of labor, and a reduction of trade barriers, broad shifts in economic activity from developed to developing countries have taken place over the past two decades. The biggest change involves a long-term shift in economic power from advanced to a handful of large developing countries that have grown twice as fast as advanced countries for more than a decade. These rising economic powers have become increasingly important generators of world economic growth.

Their share of global trade has increased significantly, with trade and investment between developing countries (South-South trade and investment) becoming an important new force in the global economy. These countries now export a diversified range of manufactured products and are actively upgrading their ability to produce more sophisticated and higher value-added products.

These trends have been accompanied by a major shift in the location of manufacturing from advanced to developing countries, particularly to Asia. Often referred to as “Factory Asia,” this development has been driven by the proliferation of global supply chains that rely on significant amounts of goods and services inputs from different countries, including from the United States.

In this new environment, countries no longer specialize exclusively in producing finished products, but rather in specific stages of the production process.
The rising economic powers have also increased their financial holdings and wealth and are becoming more important players in international financial markets.

While a dominant share of financial assets, financial centers, and financial regulatory power remains concentrated in the United States and Europe, these emerging economies have accumulated large volumes of foreign exchange reserves, established sovereign wealth funds, borrowed capital from international financial markets, attracted foreign direct investment, and begun investing some of their assets abroad. Corporations based in these countries are playing an increasingly prominent role in global business and cross-border investment, often competing with U.S. and European multinationals for natural resources, technology, and investment in other developing countries. Singapore, Hong Kong, and Shanghai are growing in importance as financial centers and will perhaps rank someday with the traditional hubs of New York, London, Frankfurt, and Tokyo. 

As their role in international trade and investment increases, demand for emerging market currencies is also likely to grow over time, perhaps paving the way for an international monetary system with more than one key reserve currency.

As a result of these changes, the long-standing division between advanced and developing countries has eroded, particularly for the handful of rising economic powers. The advanced or developed countries may still be the richest countries in terms of per capita incomes, but their economies may no longer be the largest, the fastest-growing, or the most dynamic. This development, in turn, has implications for U.S. economic well-being and global economic leadership that are subject to debate. Key changes in the global economy are documented in more detail below.

V.II.3.5 Measuring the Size of China’s Economy
The actual size of China’s economy has been a subject of debate among economists. Many economists contend that using market or nominal exchange rates to convert Chinese data (or that of other countries) into U.S. dollars fails to reflect the true size of China’s economy and living standards relative to the United States. Nominal exchange rates simply reflect the prices of foreign currencies relative to the U.S. dollar and exclude differences in the prices for goods and services across countries. To illustrate, one U.S. dollar exchanged for local currency in China would buy more goods and services there than it would in the United States.

This is because prices for goods and services in China are generally lower than they are in the United States. To make more accurate comparisons, economists attempt to develop estimates of exchange rates based on their actual purchasing power relative to the dollar. Such estimates increase the measurement of the size of China’s economy and its per capita GDP by substantial amounts.

V.II.3.6 Qualifications to the GDP Projections
These types of GDP projections should be interpreted with caution. Past projections that Russia and Japan would surpass the U.S. GDP, for example, proved far off the mark. Some economists argue, in fact, that the correlation between a country’s growth rate in one decade and the next decade is remarkably low and extrapolative forecasting can be perilous.

Each of the rising economic powers faces internal challenges or obstacles that could easily derail the long-term growth projections. China and India, the two largest and most important of the rising economic powers, stand in a class all by themselves both in terms of their potential impact on the global economy and the obstacles that could derail their growth over the next 40 years.
India’s internal challenges are no less daunting. To achieve its long-term growth potential, India may have to make progress on a wide range of economic and political reforms. According to a Goldman Sachs analysis, India needs to improve its governance, raise its educational standards, control inflation, liberalize financial markets and increase trade with its neighbours, boost agricultural productivity, and improve its infrastructure. Delivery of all of these changes will not be easy.
It should also be emphasized that these projections foresee only a relative decline in the size of the G-7 economies. In absolute and real terms, all the studies project real increases in GDP for the advanced countries. So despite rapid growth in the emerging powerhouses, their populations will remain significantly poorer than those in advanced countries. By 2050, six of the largest developing countries will have per capita incomes far below Japan, the United States, and much of Europe. U.S. per capita income will be nearly three times that of China and eight times that of India, influencing the U.S. role in a global economy. Therefore, the advanced countries that have dominated the global economy for the past 50 years will continue to maintain the highest living standards, but their leadership role may be increasingly contested by a varied group of rising economic powers.

V.II.3.7 Location of Global Manufacturing and Services
The location of global manufacturing is shifting from advanced countries to developing countries, particularly the emerging economies. Industry is accounting for a growing share of output in emerging economies, rising from 27.9% between 1960 and 1972 to 34.2% between 1986 and 2008, but it represents a declining share in advanced economies, falling from 33.6% to 28.1% in these same periods.

At the same time, industrial activity is growing at a more rapid pace in emerging economies compared to advanced economies. Industrial output in emerging economies grew 6.47% from 1960 to 1972, 5.54% between 1972 and 1985, and 6.67% between 1986 and 2008. This compares to advanced countries’ rates of industrial growth of 5.41% from 1960 to 1972, 1.65% from 1973 to 1985, and 1.78% for the 1986-2008 period. Based on the information available, a continuing shift of manufacturing activity toward emerging economies is observed.

V.II.3.9 Globalization of Production and “Factory Asia”
The transfer of manufacturing capability from advanced countries to emerging powers is also documented by the growth in Manufacturing Value Added per capita (MVA).  According to OECD calculations, the growth in manufacturing value added per capita in the emerging economies has been in excess of 6% per year since 1990 while the growth rate in advanced economies has been less than 2%. The authors maintain that there is a link between countries that have sustained strong growth in manufacturing value added and in strong economic growth.

The accumulation of manufacturing value added has been concentrated in Asia.
MVA per capita has increased nearly six-fold in China since 1990, but it has stagnated in Latin America and Sub-Saharan Africa. In 2010, China overtook the United States as the world’s largest producer of manufactured goods with a market share of 19.8%, just slightly larger than the U.S. share of 19.4%

The concentration of manufacturing in Asia (often referred to as “Factory Asia”) has been driven by outsourcing and off-shoring of production. Instead of concentrating on producing the total value of the product with domestic inputs, “Factory Asia” is characterized by fragmentation of production and supply chains incorporating a substantial amount of value added from each country involved, including the United States.

The globalization of production, of course, is not particular to Asia. As illustrated by the production of the Boeing 787 Dreamliner, parts for major capital and consumer products are increasingly sourced on a global basis. What the diagram does not show, however, is that the growing tendency of companies to contract out to other companies for the production of components and services can run into problems. In the case of the Dreamliner, Boeing’s decision in 2003 to contract out or outsource substantial production proved problematic. Many parts did not fit together and dozens of sub-contractors failed to deliver their parts on time, resulting in cost over-runs and a three-year production delay.

China, as the hub of “Factory Asia” has become competitive not only because of its lower labor costs, but also because it is a huge importer of sophisticated components from other East Asian countries for assembly and re-exports to Western markets. Its integration into global production networks is reflected in the fact that it runs bilateral trade deficits with nearly all East Asian countries and bilateral trade surpluses with most developed countries particularly the United States and European countries.

 Recognizing that their days as the lowest-cost producers of manufactured goods may not last forever, China and India are actively trying to upgrade their ability to compete in higher value added segments of manufacturing the design, innovation, and marketing of products by increasing support for research and development and technological acquisition.20 For example, since 2000, China has invested 1.4% of its GDP in R&D and India has invested 0.8%. China and India are increasing their R&D expenditures at over 8% per year, while U.S. expenditures are projected to increase by around 2%.21 The World Bank study maintains that “the location of major research facilities in China by Microsoft, the invention of Nano micro-car by Indian firm Tata, and the continued string of aeronautical breakthroughs in Russia suggest the emerging-economy giants’ strong potential for fostering growth through technological advancement.

V.II.4 New Patterns of International Trade Flows
Substantial changes in the patterns (shares, direction, and composition) of international trade flows are an important element of the changing global economic landscape. These changes are associated with the liberalization of trade policies around the world, export-led growth strategies of developing countries, the rapid declines in the costs of transportation and communication, and the impact of supply chain production and growing prominence of multinational corporations (MNCs) in world trade. 

According to the Brookings Institution study Emerging Markets, the emerging markets as a group became much more open to international trade (as measured by the ratio of total trade to GDP) over the past 25 years. Trade liberalization or reductions of trade barriers implemented either unilaterally or as a result of multilateral negotiations have increased their exposure to trade. Since 1985, the trade openness ratio of these economies has increased from less than 30% to around 80%; the similar measure for advanced countries increased from 26% to 46%. During this period, the average growth rate of exports for emerging markets was two times greater than for advanced economies. Trade flows have thus been very important for integrating emerging economies into the global economy.

V.II.4.1 International Finance

V.II.4.1.1 Strengthening International Frameworks for Financial Integration
Strengthening international frameworks for financial integration may become more important with growing global interconnectedness, particularly with developing countries’ rising role in foreign direct investment, bank loans, and portfolio flows. While the increasing weight of developing countries in global asset portfolios will help residents of advanced countries earn higher returns on their foreign investments and improve diversification, a financial crisis in either developing or advanced countries is likely to have global repercussions, as the Asian financial crisis in the late 1990s and the 2008-2009 financial crisis demonstrated. As these countries grow much larger, the risks remain as their financial sectors are still small and relatively undeveloped.

Thus, it may be in the interest of advanced countries to support improvements in the institutions and rules to ensure prudential risk-taking including capital requirements, limitations on the kinds of business commercial banks can conduct, transparency requirements, and rules governing derivative requirements. To move in this direction, developing countries may need to be part of any rebalancing of the global financial regulatory landscape.

The Basel 3 capital accord, announced in 2010, may be the last prominent piece of international financial rulemaking whose negotiation took place mainly among developed countries. Several financial bodies, including the Basel Committee and the Financial Stability Board, have now enlarged their membership to include many of the rising economic powers. 

Incorporating the rising economic powers into global financial bodies may not be easy. As in the trade arena, some emerging powers are quick to see the opportunities, but not the responsibilities it creates for them. Some observers suspect that Western-driven regulation may be a way for the more established financial centers and firms to freeze the competitive playing field and prevent the rise of new entrants. On the other hand, some in the United States and Europe fear that as they re-regulate their financial systems as a consequence of the crisis, developing countries could attract business “unfairly” based on less demanding rules.

V.II.4.1.2 Rules for Foreign Direct Investment and rate of exchange
Beginning with a League of Nations conference in 1929, there have been many unsuccessful efforts to negotiate a multilateral investment framework. Difficulties in achieving consensus across different levels of economic development and different definitions of investor rights and protections are some of the reasons past efforts have been unsuccessful.

The rapid increase in FDI flows since the early 1970s, combined with the growing importance of developing country multinationals, could, however, increase support for another attempt at establishing a multilateral framework for foreign investment. This view assumes that as the importance of foreign investment grows for developing countries and developing country multinationals, the need for a multilateral framework that provides adequate legal protection for foreign investors will become more apparent to many of the stakeholders who have opposed such attempts in the past.

In the absence of a multilateral framework on foreign direct investment flows, bilateral investment treaties (BITs) have proliferated worldwide and become the dominant mechanism governing such flows. Over the past three decades, the number of BITs negotiated has increased more than tenfold, rising from about 200 in 1980 to 2,275 in 2007. Investors’ contractual rights, allow for repatriation of profits, and provide a mechanism for disputes and international arbitration. While BITs, on balance, may improve the investment climate, the large number of BITs arguably increases the complexity of rules for foreign investment and the costs of compliance.  

In most of underdeveloped countries we face money depreciation.
In what concerns the rate of exchange, we should distinguish between the real rates of exchange and nominal rates of exchange. A nominal rate of exchange is the relative cost between 2 countries. For instance (1$→750→) certain quotation of foreign currency with local currency, the opposite is called uncertain quotation 750 Frw= 1$

1Frw= 1/750= 0,001333333. However, the real rate of exchange is the relative cost of goods between two countries and it is calculated in the following way.

Real rate of exchange=                                                                          RRE=  E.g.: A car coats 1500 US $ in the USA, Currency Exchange is 1$= 750 Frw

A car coats 1,050,000 Frw in Rwanda without Taxes and others Expense, Transportation from USA up to Rwanda is 500.000 Frw, Taxes and Others Expenses 500.000 Frw

After Giving the Value of this car in Rwanda Calculate the Real Rate of Exchange?
The Value of this Car in Rwanda is 1.050.000+500.000+500.000= 2.050.000 Frw
750 Frw= 1$, 1 Frw= , 1 Frw = 0,001333333$

Real rate of exchange (RRE) =  0,001333333$*2.050.000/1500= 1.82. When RRE is 1, this means that the good is expensive inside the country.

The Nominal Rate of Exchange NRE is an average annual rate of the official market in terms of national currency compared to a foreign currency of reference , there the US $.
Fluctuations of change are everywhere the characteristics of developing countries (DC). There often exist currency fall in value in that country.

V.II.4.1.3 Operation of Sovereign Wealth Funds and State-Owned Multinationals
Operating as investment funds owned and managed by national governments, sovereign wealth funds (SWFs) have been created since the 1950s by oil- and resource-producing countries to stabilize their economies against fluctuating commodity prices and to provide a source of wealth for future generations. 

More recently, the shift of wealth from advanced countries to emerging economies in which governments play a large role in the management of economic activity has allowed a number of countries, mostly Asian (China, Japan, Singapore, and Korea), to create SWFs by diverting foreign exchange reserves from other than natural resources proceeds. The fact that the policies that led to some of the accumulations of foreign exchange reserves have been internationally criticized suggests that the activities of these SWFs will be more closely scrutinized than the SWFs of other countries.

While the standard objective of most SWFs is to maximize their “risk-adjusted financial return” by investing in a broader array of assets than U.S. Treasury bills, concerns have surfaced that such investments may also be motivated by pursuit of national political or economic power. Some U.S. policymakers have expressed concerns that countries will use SWFs to secure strategic assets around the world in areas such as telecommunications, energy resources, and financial services.

Some of these concerns may have lessened in recent years due to the adoption in 2008 of voluntary guidelines by 26 countries, including China, Singapore, and South Korea. Known as the Santiago Principles, these guidelines seek to increase the transparency and disclosure requirements of the SWFs. However, the size of some Asian SWFs alone (e.g., China Investment

Corporation has $332 billion in assets and Singapore’s Investment Corporation has $248 billion) suggests these concerns will not disappear quickly.
Some of the same issues may arise regarding state-owned multinational companies. While there is no reason on the surface that firms such as China’s Lenovo should be treated any differently by host country national authorities, the implicit backing that these firms have from their governments may give them some unfair advantages in terms of financing and market power.

V.II.4.1.4 Future of the Dollar as the Primary Reserve Currency
Since the United States emerged as the world’s preeminent power a century ago, the dollar has become the world’s main currency for carrying out international transactions. Oil and virtually all other commodities in international markets are bought and sold in dollars. In addition, the dollar is the main currency in which most countries hold their monetary reserves an arrangement that has costs and benefits for the United States.

The ongoing shifts in the balance of international economic power, however, are raising questions about the continued dominance of the dollar. China and Russia, two rising economic powers, have called for an end to the long reign of the dollar as the world’s reserve currency. They argue that an international monetary system in which the dollar, the euro, and China’s Ren Minbi (RMB) share the reserve currency role will be an improvement over the system where countries seeking to accumulate reserves have no alternative to accumulating dollars.

 In 2010, the RMB played a negligible role in global currency markets, accounting for less than 1% of foreign exchange market turnover. By contrast, the U.S. dollar figured in 85% of transactions, the euro in 39%, and the Japanese yen in 19%. The RMB clearly has years to go before it reaches the market level with secondary currencies like the Australian dollar and Swiss franc, let alone joining the ranks of major currencies.

Functioning of the Global Economy: Reform of the Bretton Woods Institutions
The United States was a prime mover in the creation of the so-called Bretton Woods international economic institutions, including the IMF, the World Bank, and the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (now the World Trade Organization) more than a half-century ago. These institutions, premised on the values of open markets, trade liberalization, financial stability, and the rule of law, were designed to promote post-war reconstruction and a prosperous and stable global economy.

The current shift in economic and political power has occasioned a debate on the reform of these institutions, as well as on the very foundation of the post-World War II open global international economic system. Many rising developing countries want more power and influence in setting the rules and institutional arrangements of the world economy. They see existing arrangements as preserving the status quo and maintaining U.S. and, particularly, European power at the expense of developing countries.100 although the IMF and World Bank have taken some steps to increase representation to reflect the shift in economic power toward developing countries, many rising powers remain unsatisfied.

It remains to be seen whether and how the governance and functioning of these institutions for international cooperation can be reformed to become more representative of the new global landscape while retaining Western norms and values. The establishment of the G-20 as the principal forum of international policy coordination is deemed by many observers as the most promising recognition of the problem and institutional response to date. Most proposals to provide greater representativeness to these institutions call for European countries, and not the United States, to give up some of their power.

The WTO is in a unique position given that it is the only Bretton Woods institution to use the principle of “one country, one vote.” While this is a strength from the point of view of democratic representation, it also makes decision making more cumbersome.

V.II.4.1.5 Role of the G-20
Established initially in 1999 to facilitate discussions among finance ministers, the G-20 started meeting at the leader level (Summits) in September 2009 in response to the global financial crisis.  The crisis starkly illustrated the need for fiscally strapped advanced economies to rely on increases in government spending from cash-rich developing countries to keep the global economy from entering into a depression. Representing two-thirds of the world’s population, 90% of world GDP, and 80% of world trade, the G-20 has come to symbolize the growing diffusion of economic power and the fact that the advanced countries do not have the capacity to manage global economic problems alone.

With much broader representation than its predecessor coordinating groups (the G-7 and the G-8), the G-20 has the potential to fill a large gap in global economic governance by creating coalitions that cut across advanced and developing country lines. Working groups on issues such as global imbalances are co-chaired by representatives from both camps, thereby giving each side opportunities to develop reforms and establish buy-in among their respective constituencies. In addition, the G-20 has pushed other international institutions to increase the representation of developing countries.

To strengthen international standards of global finance, the G-20 replaced the Financial Stability Forum, which included only G-7 members, with the Financial Stability Board, which included developing countries. And the G-20 has worked to ensure that developing countries gain greater representation at the IMF and World Bank and that the Doha Round of multilateral trade negotiations be brought to a successful conclusion.

While the G-20 has received high marks for its response to the global economic crisis through its decisions regarding fiscal stimulus, regulatory reform, and a tripling IMF’s resources, it is uncertain that such a diverse grouping of leaders will be able to reach agreements on global economic issues that tend to be viewed in “win-lose” terms. It is also unclear how the G-20, by including only the large rising economic powers, can support multilateralism. Moreover, given that the G-20 lacks enforcement powers and a permanent institutionalized bureaucracy, commitments agreed to at summits can easily be ignored or remain unimplemented. To wit, despite several G-20 declarations urging a rapid conclusion of the Doha Round of trade negotiations, the stalemate endures.

V.III Globalizations
Globalization is the process of international integration arising from the interchange of world views, products, ideas, and other aspects of culture. Globalization describes the interplay across cultures of macro-social forces. These forces include religion, politics, and economics. Globalization can erode and universalize the characteristics of a local group. Advances in transportation and telecommunications infrastructure, including the rise of the Internet, are major factors in globalization, generating further interdependence of economic and cultural activities.

Though several scholars place the origins of globalization in modern times, others trace its history long before the European age of discovery and voyages to the New World. Some even trace the origins to the third millennium BCE. Since the beginning of the 20th century, the pace of globalization has proceeded at a rapid rate.

The term globalization has been in increasing use since the mid-1980s and especially since the mid-1990s.  In 2000, the International Monetary Fund (IMF) identified four basic aspects of globalization: trade and transactions, capital and investment movements, migration and movement of people and the dissemination of knowledge. 

Further, environmental challenges such as climate change, cross-boundary water and air pollution, and over-fishing of the ocean are linked with globalization. Globalizing processes affect and are affected by business and work organization, economics, socio-cultural resources, and the natural environment.

Humans have interacted over long distances for thousands of years. The overland Silk Road that connected Asia, Africa and Europe is a good example of the transformative power of international exchange that existed in the "Old World".

Philosophy, religion, language, the arts, and other aspects of culture spread and mixed as nations exchanged products and ideas. In the 15th and 16th centuries, Europeans made important discoveries in their exploration of the oceans, including the start of transatlantic travel to the "New World" of the Americas. Global movement of people, goods, and ideas expanded significantly in the following centuries. Early in the 19th century, the development of new forms of transportation (such as the steamship and railroads) and telecommunications that "compressed" time and space allowed for increasingly rapid rates of global interchange.

In the 20th century, road vehicles and airlines made transportation even faster, and the advent of electronic communications, most notably mobile phones and the Internet, connected billions of people in new ways leading into the 21st century.

V.III.2 Brics
originally "BRIC" before the inclusion of South Africa in 2010, is the title of an association of emerging national economies: Brazil, Russia, India, China and South Africa. With the possible exception of Russia, the BRICS members are all developing or newly industrialised countries, but they are distinguished by their large, fast-growing economies and significant influence on regional and global affairs. As of 2013, the five BRICS countries represent almost 3 billion people, with a combined nominal GDP of US$14.9 trillion, and an estimated US$4 trillion in combined foreign reserves. Presently, South Africa holds the chair of the BRICS group.

In 2012, Hu Jintao, who at the time was President of China, described the BRICS countries as defenders and promoters of developing countries and a force for world peace. However, some analysts have highlighted potential divisions and weaknesses in the grouping, such as India and China's disagreements over territorial issues, slowing growth rates, and disputes between the members over UN Security Council reform.

The foreign ministers of the initial four BRIC states (Brazil, Russia, India, and China) met in New York City in September 2006, beginning a series of high-level meetings. A full-scale diplomatic meeting was held in Yekaterinburg, Russia, on May 16, 2008.

V.III.2.1 First BRIC summit
The BRIC grouping's first formal summit commenced in Yekaterinburg on June 16, 2009, with Luiz Inácio Lula da Silva, Dmitry Medvedev, Manmohan Singh, and Hu Jintao, the respective leaders of Brazil, Russia, India and China, all attending. The summit's focus was on means of improving the global economic situation and reforming financial institutions, and discussed how the four countries could better co-operate in the future. There was further discussion of ways that developing countries, such as the BRIC members, could become more involved in global affairs.

In the aftermath of the Yekaterinburg summit, the BRIC nations announced the need for a new global reserve currency, which would have to be 'diversified, stable and predictable' Although the statement that was released did not directly criticise the perceived 'dominance' of the US dollar something that Russia had criticised in the past it did spark a fall in the value of the dollar against other major currencies.

V.III.2.2 Entry of South Africa
In 2010, South Africa began efforts to join the BRIC grouping, and the process for its formal admission began in August of that year. South Africa officially became a member nation on December 24, 2010, after being formally invited by the BRIC countries to join the group. The group was renamed BRICS – with the "S" standing for South Africa to reflect the group's expanded membership. In April 2011, the President of South Africa, Jacob Zuma, attended the 2011 BRICS summit in Sanya, China, as a full member.

V.III.2.3 Developments
The BRICS Forum, an independent international organisation encouraging commercial, political and cultural cooperation between the BRICS nations, was formed in 2011. In June 2012, the BRICS nations pledged $75 billion to boost the International Monetary Fund's lending power. However, this loan was conditional on IMF voting reforms. In late March 2013, during the fifth BRICS summit in Durban, South Africa, the member countries agreed to create a global financial institution which would rival the western-dominated IMF.

V.III.2.4 Summits
The grouping has held annual summits since 2009, with member countries taking turns to host. Prior to South Africa's admission, two BRIC summits were held, in 2009 and 2010. The first five-member BRICS summit was held in 2011. The most recent BRICS summit took place in Durban, South Africa, in March 2013.